Journal of Systems Engineering and Electronics ›› 2024, Vol. 35 ›› Issue (1): 130-153.doi: 10.23919/JSEE.2023.000160
• SYSTEMS ENGINEERING • Previous Articles
Ruihan ZHANG1,*(), Bing SUN2()
Received:
2021-03-15
Online:
2024-02-18
Published:
2024-03-05
Contact:
Ruihan ZHANG
E-mail:ruihanzhang@dhu.edu.cn;heusun@hotmail.com
About author:
Supported by:
Ruihan ZHANG, Bing SUN. Complex adaptive system theory, agent-based modeling, and simulation in dominant technology formation[J]. Journal of Systems Engineering and Electronics, 2024, 35(1): 130-153.
Add to citation manager EndNote|Reference Manager|ProCite|BibTeX|RefWorks
Table 1
Main equations of variable relationships"
Number | Equation | Unit | Category |
1 | Number of 5G mobile phone users = INTEG (new increment of 5G mobile phone users, the initial number of 5G mobile phone users) | Ten thousand | Level variable |
2 | New increment of 5G mobile phone users= annual output of 5G mobile phone users × consumption intention of 5G mobile phone users | 10000/year | Rate variable |
3 | Consumption intention of 5G mobile phone users = price influence of 5G traffic + word-of-mouth influence + advertising influence + price influence of 5G mobile phone users | Dmnl | Auxiliary variable |
4 | Total benefit of 5G mobile phone users = (purchase price-production cost) × the number of 5G mobile phone users | Ten thousand yuan | Auxiliary variable |
5 | Cumulative investment in the 5G mobile phone user industry chain = INTEG (total benefit of 5G mobile phone users × production reinvestment coefficient of manufacturer’s profit + government subsidies × distribution coefficient of manufacturer’s financial subsidy, cumulative investment in the initial 5G mobile phone user industry chain) | Ten thousand yuan | Level variable |
6 | Research and development investment = cumulative investment in the 5G mobile phone user industry chain × research and development investment coefficient | Ten thousand yuan | Auxiliary variable |
7 | Technology level = research and development investment/research and development investment transformation | Individual | Auxiliary variable |
8 | Infrastructure perfection coefficient = number of 5G mobile phone users/number of 5G base stations | Individual | Auxiliary variable |
9 | Per capita disposable income = gross domestic product/populations | 10000 yuan/person | Auxiliary variable |
10 | Total gross domestic product = INTEG (gross domestic product growth, initial gross domestic product) | One hundred million yuan | Level variable |
11 | Gross domestic product growth = total gross domestic product × annual gross domestic product growth rate | Ten thousand yuan | Rate variable |
12 | Annual gross domestic product growth rate | Dmnl | Constant |
13 | Total population = INTEG (population growth, initial population) | 100 million people | Level variable |
14 | Population growth = total population × annual population growth rate | Ten thousand people | Rate variable |
15 | Annual population growth rate | Dmnl | Constant |
16 | Number of 5G base stations= INTEG (growth of 5G base stations, number of initial 5G base stations) | Individual | Level variable |
17 | 5G base station increase = infrastructure construction investment × investment conversion | 10000 yuan / piece | Rate variable |
18 | Infrastructure improvement coefficient = number of 5G base stations/number of 5G mobile phone users | Dmnl | Auxiliary variable |
19 | Product attraction factor = technology level + infrastructure perfection | Dmnl | Auxiliary variable |
20 | Purchase price = unit production cost × (1 + supply chain profit margin)-government subsidy × consumer financial subsidy distribution coefficient | Ten thousand yuan | Auxiliary variable |
21 | Supply chain profit margin | Dmnl | Constant |
22 | Purchase subsidy | Dmnl | Constant |
23 | 5G data price reduction value =5G data price reduction rate ×5G data price | Ten thousand yuan/ year | Rate variable |
24 | 5G data price = INTEG (5G data price reduction value, 5G data price) | Ten thousand yuan | Level variable |
25 | Distribution coefficient of manufacturer’s financial subsidy | Dmnl | Table functions |
26 | 5G data price reduction rate | Dmnl | Table functions |
27 | Government subsidy = INTEG (increase rate of government subsidy, government subsidy) | Ten thousand yuan | Level variable |
28 | Distribution coefficient of consumer financial subsidies | Dmnl | Table functions |
29 | Increase rate of government subsidies = government subsidies × growth coefficient of government subsidies | Ten thousand yuan/ year | Rate variable |
30 | Government subsidies or preferential policies | Dmnl | Table functions |
31 | 5G data price impact | Dmnl | Table functions |
32 | Annual output of 5G mobile phone = production input / unit production cost | Individual | Auxiliary variable |
33 | Production investment = cumulative investment in 5G mobile phone industrialization × proportion of capital investment for production | Ten thousand yuan | Auxiliary variable |
34 | 5G technology patent application = INTEGER (5G technology patent increase, 5G technology patent application) | Individual | Level variable |
35 | Increase in 5G technology patents = research and development investment × investment conversion rate + technology level | Per/year | Rate variable |
36 | 5G baseband chip production = INTEG (5G baseband chip added value, 5G baseband chip production) | Ten thousand | Level variable |
37 | Added value of 5G baseband chip = accumulated investment in 5G mobile phone industrialization × proportion of investment in research and development and production of chip | Ten thousand/year | Rate variable |
38 | Degree of perfection of 5G network related hardware = 1 / (production of 5G supporting antenna + production of 5G baseband chip) | Dmnl | Auxiliary variable |
1 | ABERNATHY W J, UTTERBACK J Patterns of industrial innovation. Technology Review, 1978, 80 (7): 40- 47. |
2 |
SUAREZ F F, UTTERBACK J M Dominant designs and the survival of firms. Strategic Management Journal, 1995, 16 (6): 415- 430.
doi: 10.1002/smj.4250160602 |
3 | CHRISTENSE C M, SUAREZ F, UTTERBACK J M Strategies for survival in fast-changing industries. Management Science, 1998, 44 (12): 207- 220. |
4 |
SUAREZ F F Battles for technological dominance: an integrative framework. Research Policy, 2004, 33 (2): 271- 286.
doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2003.07.001 |
5 | HOLLAND J H. Hidden order: how adaptation builds complexity. New York: Addison Wesley, 1995. |
6 |
LOPOLITO A, MORONE P, TAYLOR R Emerging innovation niches: an agent based model. Research Policy, 2013, 42 (6/7): 1225- 1238.
doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2013.03.002 |
7 | BERGMAN N, HAXELTINE A, WHITMARSH L. Modelling socio-technical transition patterns and pathways. Journal of Artificial Societies & Social Simulation, 2008, 11(3): 29. |
8 | ZHANG F W The research for the attachment of coal industry’s related technology and leading technology. China Mining Magine, 2010, 19 (6): 41- 43. |
9 | TUSHAMN M L, ANDERSON P Technological discontinuities and dominant designs. Administrative Science Quarterly, 1990, 35, 604- 633. |
10 | FERNANDEZ E, VALLE S Battle for dominant design: a decision-making model. European Research on Management & Business Economics, 2019, 25 (2): 72- 78. |
11 | WU D Y, ZHANG Z J Dominant design: the new paradigm of market entry barriers. East China Economic Management, 2006, 4, 126- 129. |
12 | LIU H Y, PENG F Y, WU C S. The formation mechanism and growth path of strategic emerging industries. Science & Technology Progress and Policy, 2012, 29(11): 46−49. |
13 | LU J Z Development direction of agricultural science and technology in China during new era and important proposition analysis. Journal of Agricultural Science and Technology, 2014, 16 (6): 1- 6. |
14 | CHESBROUGH H Arrested developmen: the experience of European hard disk drive firms in comparison with US and Japanese firms. Evolutionary Economics, 1999, 9, 287- 329. |
15 | SRINIVASAN R, LILIEN G L, RANGASWAMY A The emergence of dominant designs. Journal of Marketing, 2006, 70 (2): 1- 17. |
16 | TAN J, XUE H Z The formation mechanism of dominant design and its contributing strategic factors. Chinese Soft Science, 2007, 7, 41- 53. |
17 | LI D, LIU W, SONG Z Appropriablity strategy, technology flexibility and the emergence of dominant designs: a comparative case study. Science & Technology Progress and Policy, 2019, 36 (11): 1- 8. |
18 | MIU X M, ZHAO H The roles of government in the evolution of dominant design: study based on China’s telecom industry. Journal of Information, 2008, 11, 155- 158. |
19 | DAI H, ZENG D, QUALLS J W, et al Do social ties matter for the emergence of dominant design? The moderating roles of technological turbulence and IRP enforcement. Journal of Engineering and Technology Management, 2018, 47, 96- 109. |
20 | BREM A, NYLUND P, VIARDOT E The impact of the 2008 financial crisis on innovation: a dominant design perspective. Journal of Business Research, 2020, 110, 360- 369. |
21 |
GEELS F W Technological transitions as evolutionary reconfiguration processes: a multi-level perspective and a case study. Research Policy, 2002, 31 (8/9): 1257- 1274.
doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(02)00062-8 |
22 |
SMITH A, VOSS J P, GRIN J Innovation studies and sustainability transitions: the allure of the multi-level perspective and its challenges. Research Policy, 2010, 39 (4): 435- 448.
doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2010.01.023 |
23 | GEELS F W Disruption and low-carbon system transformation: Progress and new challenges in socio-technical transitions research and the multi-level perspective. Energy Research & Social Science, 2018, 37, 224- 231. |
24 | RIP A, KEMP R. Technological change. RAYNER S, MALONE E L, ed. Human choice and climate change. Ohio: Battelle Press, 1998. |
25 | HEKKERT M, HOED R V D Competing technologies and the struggle towards a new dominant design. Greener Management International, 2004, 47 (16): 28- 43. |
26 |
ANDERSON P, TUSHMAN M L Technological discontinuities and dominant designs: a cyclical model of technological change. Administrative Science Quarterly, 1990, 35 (4): 604- 633.
doi: 10.2307/2393511 |
27 | BREM A, NYLUND A P, SCHUSTER G Innovation and de facto standardization: the influence of dominant design on innovative performance, radical innovation, and process innovation. Technovation, 2016, 50, 79- 88. |
28 | MURMANN J P, FRENKEN K Toward a systematic framework for research on dominant designs, technological innovations, and industrial change. Research Policy, 2006, 35, 925- 952. |
29 |
UTTERBACK J M, ABERNATHY W J A dynamic model of process and product innovation. Omega, 1975, 3 (6): 639- 656.
doi: 10.1016/0305-0483(75)90068-7 |
30 | BERKELEY N, BAILEY D, JONES A, et al Assessing the transition towards battery electric vehicles: a multilevel perspective on drivers of, and barriers to, take up. Transportation Research Part A Policy & Practice, 2017, 106, 320- 332. |
31 | HOLLAND J H. Complex adaptive system. Reading: Addison Wesley, 1995. |
32 |
HAURAND M D, STUMMER C Stakes or garlic? Studying the emergence of dominant designs through an agent-based model of a vampire economy. Central European Journal of Operations Research, 2018, 26 (2): 373- 394.
doi: 10.1007/s10100-017-0492-9 |
33 |
RAND W M, RUST R T Agent-based modeling in marketing: guidelines for rigor. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 2011, 28 (3): 181- 193.
doi: 10.1016/j.ijresmar.2011.04.002 |
34 | AHRWEILER P, PYKA A, GILBERT N. Simulating knowledge dynamics in innovation networks (SKIN). LEOMBRUNI R, RICHIARDI M, ed. Industry and labor dynamics: the agent-based computational economics approach. Singapore: World Scientific Press, 2004. |
35 | MA Q, WU W W, LIU Y X, et al Impact of the synergy between technology management and technological capability on new product development: a system dynamics approach. Journal of Systems Engineering and Electronics, 2022, 33 (1): 105- 119. |
No related articles found! |
Viewed | ||||||
Full text |
|
|||||
Abstract |
|
|||||